Reclaim Democracy!

  • Home
  • Issues
    • The Right to Vote
      • U.S. Voting History
      • 50+ Ways to Disenfranchise or Suppress Voters
    • Corporate Personhood
    • Citizens United
    • Direct Democracy
    • All Topics
  • Resources
    • Ed Board Meetings
    • Letters to the Editor
    • Op-eds
    • Presentations & Workshops
    • Talk Radio
    • Tools for Activism
  • Donate
  • About
  • Contact

The Benefits of Buying Locally

July 14, 2012 by staff

Each year brings more national chains displacing locally-owned businesses throughout the country. We see clones replace unique establishments. People across the country are losing sense of community in their town, and consider this trend a symptom, but could it be a cause as well? Also, what are the impacts of this trend on our economic well-being?

It seems obvious that we do business where we perceive we receive the best value for our time and money. Perceptions, however, are not always accurate when we are lacking some of the essential information for fully informed decisions. We see and hear the omnipresent ads of corporate chains everyday, but are collectively under-informed about the many important values independent businesses provide us individually and as a community.

Some economists would call the chain encroachment a natural trend. Tough for the family who owns the small business, but it doesn’t really affect the economy. Overall sales may even go up a little when a chain drives out a small independent, so what’s the problem?

The disappearance of local businesses leaves a social and economic void that is palpable and real – even when it is unmeasured. The quality of life of a community changes in ways that macroeconomics is slow to measure, or ignores completely. Let’s look at some of the issues.

1. Building A Strong Local Economy –  The giant chains often win a town’s consent to build new stores with promises of growth and tax revenues. But when communities such as St Albans, VT & New Paltz, NY performed thorough analyses, they concluded proposed new “big box” retailers would create economic costs exceeding benefits, (loss of existing jobs and increased infrastructure demands being the top two) and wisely rejected them on those grounds. They are among more than 90 [now 200] communities around the country to have such foresight in recent years. Their scrutiny inevitably shows that most income of new chains comes directly from established businesses. For example, an extensive study of new Wal-Marts at Iowa State University found 84% of sales simply shifted dollars away from existing local merchants.

It’s time to consider the real costs to a community that loses its local business base. Independent local businesses employ a wide array of supporting services. They hire architects, designers, cabinet shops, sign makers and contractors for construction. Opportunities grow for local accountants, insurance brokers, computer consultants, attorneys, advertising agencies and others to help run it. Local retailers and distributors also carry a higher percentage of locally-made goods than the chains, creating more jobs for local producers.

In contrast, a new chain store typically puts in place a clone of other units, eliminates the need for local planning, and uses a minimum of local goods and services. In a company-owned store, the profits are promptly exported to corporate headquarters. These factors lead local independent merchants create a multiplier effect in the local economy of 3 – 3 1/2 times that of a chain outlet (the multiplier difference in non-retail businesses is generally lower, but no less important).While many communities focus on sales tax revenue, we need to remember that the one-time tax revenue is only one part of the economic picture.

Small manufacturers are also affected since they rely on local retailers to give their new products a chance. Local retailers are more free to take chances with the goods of a new manufacturer, or a product that is not part of a national sales plan. Therefore, small manufacturers and a wide variety of service industries have a clear stake in the nationwide health of local retailers.

In the larger picture, sales of the 500 largest corporations grew 700% in the past 20 years, yet those corporations are now net disemployers, firing more people than they hire despite record profits. That our economy is still in decent health is testimony to the employment generated by small business during this time. We need to recognize the impact of our dollars and support institutions that benefit our common interests.

2. Ensuring Choice and Diversity –  Retailers sift through competing goods and services to find those that appeal to their customers. Even though a single local shop may have a smaller selection than a big chain outlet, a multiplicity of independent retailers creates great diversity.

For example, when 3,000 or so national independent booksellers or music shops buy for their local customers’ tastes, the cumulative effect is demand for a wide variety of ideas and music. This makes accessible controversial books or music from new artists with the expectation that there will be a market somewhere within a variety of stores. As fewer giant corporations dominate both production and sales, our options – determined by a powerful few – will be drastically reduced.

Our freedom of choice is imperiled when a few buyers from national chains choose what reaches consumers. This may be only mildly disturbing for most consumer goods, but truly frightening when you consider the impact on our choice of news sources, books, music and other modes of expression.

3. Maintaining Community Character –  When asked to name our favorite restaurant, cafe, or shop, we almost always cite a unique local business (look at the results in any “Best of” polls as proof). We embrace the idea of distinctive businesses with local character, but often forget their survival depends on our patronage. It is easy for us to get so consumed by efficiency that we forget how much of our lives we spend eating out, shopping, and doing other business. We owe it to ourselves to consider the quality of our experience, and ask if we benefit when we choose a community-based business.

Local owners with much of their life savings invested in their businesses have a natural interest in the long-term health of the community. Community-based businesses are essential to charitable endeavors, frequently serving on local boards, and supporting a variety of causes. Yes, there are some corporate chains that give back to towns in which they do business, but anyone who raises funds for local non-profits will tell you that independents are their base of support. Not all local businesses are models to follow, and corporate chains are not inherently bad, but the overall impacts are clear: local businesses play a vital role in our community that corporate chains rarely do, while chains often even undermine community interests.

Recurring Problems

The loss of local businesses hasn’t just resulted from free market economics; it’s had plenty of help. Favoritism from large manufacturers toward corporate chains such as “promotional allowances” (free advertising), takes different forms, many of them illegal under anti-trust laws. Enforcement of these laws, created to protect consumers and communities, is an important step in solving these problems.

Local officials nationwide often fall for the seductions and political appeal of luring new national chains. They often look at promises of jobs and tax revenues, but fail to consider the greater losses that occur when the local business base is undermined. We see examples nationwide of tax and regulatory breaks worth millions used to lure out-of state corporations. Why should these businesses enjoy favors that our community-based businesses do not?

Let’s make future decisions based on full-cost accounting, and create a level (or better) playing field for local businesses with our policies; the chains already have enough laws rigged in their favor nationally.

Hope For The Future

For long-term progress, a conceptual change also is necessary. We need to consciously plan that future with rules that will encourage the values we want reflected in our communities. And each time we spend a dollar, we would do well to weigh the full value of our choices, not solely to ourselves immediately, but for the future we want in our own hometowns.

By Jeff Milchen, former executive director of Reclaim Democracy and co-founder of the American Independent Business Alliance (AMIBA). Please contact AMIBA for reprint permission (and updates to the article) or for assistance launching buy local campaigns or other initiatives to support community-based enterprise.

Help fund our cause by buying one of our corporate logo flags (the American flag with corporate logos in place of the stars) – it’ll show your objection to corporate personhood and raise awareness.

Filed Under: Independent Business

Book Review: Big Box Swindle

December 31, 2006 by staff

Published December 31, 2006

Stacy Mitchell’s new book, Big Box Swindle, offers a compelling case for why uncontrolled proliferation of corporate chains undermines communities, competitive markets, and democracy. Mitchell provides a fine balance by detailing the big picture with extensive research while driving home the impact of problems with stories of real people, businesses and communities.

An especially interesting chapter is “Uncle Sam’s Invisible Hand,” which reveals how government policies have played an immense role in shaping the retail and other commercial development. Some of these policies, such as directly subsidizing politically powerful corporations, may be familiar to our readers, but Mitchell unearths many cases of more subtle government favoritism or discrimination that make clear the growth of corporate chains has not resulted from market forces alone.

Equally valuable, Mitchell details a wealth of positive and concrete measures that independent businesses and communities are taking to support hometown businesses and keep opportunities for entrepreneurs alive. This is not the brief “wish list” we too often see concluding books about the problems with corporate power, but real stories of viable solutions and who is creating them.

This isn’t surprising, since Mitchell works for the Institute for Local Self-Reliance and chairs the board of directors of the American Independent Business Alliance — two organizations leading localization efforts in the U.S.

Mitchell’s first book, The Home Town Advantage, quickly earned our recommendation, but in addition to having the most up-to-date data and examples, Swindle surpasses her earlier effort in breadth, depth and quality of narrative. After an opening chapter that’s interesting, but heavy on data, Mitchell’s engaging stories make Swindle a compelling read.

Big Box Swindle is one of the most important books in years. We encourage you to not only read it, but get it into the hands of friends, family and opinion leaders in your community

If you lack an independent book store in your town, you can order directly from our merchandise page or from the website (Beacon Press, 2006. $25 hardcover). Inquire for discount on multiple copies.

See BigBoxSwindle.com for additional reviews and Stacy Mitchell’s speaking schedule.

Filed Under: Independent Business

Don’t Believe the Hype

October 18, 2006 by staff

Media Promotes Prescription Drug Pricing Stunts at Wal-Mart and Other Mass Merchants While Ignoring Hidden Costs

By Jeff Milchen and Stacy Mitchell
October, 2006. First published in the Providence Journal

When Wal-Mart issued a press release announcing some generic drugs would be sold for $4 at Tampa area stores, its executives undoubtedly hoped for some favorable publicity in Florida media. Instead, they received sweeping headlines across many states like “Wal-Mart to sell generic drugs for $4 a month”— often on page one of major newspapers.

After getting better advertising than even a multi-billion dollar corporation can buy, Wal-Mart naturally decided to milk the publicity by announcing drug discounts in most other states a few at a time. Sure enough, Wal-Mart enjoyed wave after wave of free publicity.

But was Wal-Mart’s promotion really headline news?

First, Wal-Mart is not offering the deal on most generic drugs. Though the corporation issued a 300+ item list of $4 drugs, most items were different dosages and configurations (pills and capsules listed separately), not unique medications. Twelve different variations of the common antibiotic amoxicillin are listed, along with multiple dosages of ibuprofen — already widely available for less than $4.

Unique medications totaled 124 among a few thousand commonly available prescription drugs and those discounted drugs make up less than one-quarter of prescriptions Wal-Mart dispenses and only one of the ten most common generic medications is included in its $4 promotion. But Wal-Mart’s decision to discount a small portion of one product line generated priceless publicity for the corporation’s “low price” image.

The impact was huge and immediate. A poll by the Wall Street Journal found just 13 percent of respondents indicated Wal-Mart or other mass merchants were their usual destination for filling drug prescriptions. After the barrage of media coverage for Wal-Mart’s PR stunt and matching offers by other mass merchants, a stunning 50 percent of those respondents said they would be likely, very likely or “absolutely certain” to fill prescriptions at these stores.

They should think twice.

True, some people who need one of the chosen drugs will save money. But unless shoppers check Wal-Mart’s list in advance, they’re likely to become victims of a bait-and-switch. Consumer Reports magazine repeatedly has found independent pharmacies beating Wal-Mart and every chain drugstore on price in their periodic investigations (see a summary of their 2018 survey).

Contrary to common perception, the evidence overwhelmingly indicates independent pharmacies, not Wal-Mart or other chains, offer the best value.

In 2003, the state of Maine researched prices of 15 common prescription drugs at independent and chain pharmacies of all kinds statewide. The 10 lowest-priced pharmacies all were independents, beating all five Wal-Marts in the study. Studies by New York City and the Senior Action Council in New York also showed lower drug pricing at independents than chains.

So don’t assume the buying power of chains translates into lower price. Through group purchasing efforts, independent pharmacies compete vigorously on price and do it while offering more than just pills. In 2003, the venerable Consumer Reports magazine surveyed 32,000 readers about their experiences at thousands of pharmacies, including independents, chains and those within supermarkets and mass merchants.

Though mass merchants had an edge on price alone, independents trounced the big boxes (as well as supermarket and drug chains) in overall value by “an eye-popping margin.”

The survey found independents were more likely than all chain stores to have a needed medication, got out-of-stock drugs faster, and provided more personal attention.

And personal service from your neighborhood drugstore means more than asking “how’s the family?” For anyone taking multiple medications, their pharmacist’s attention can be crucial to avoiding dangerous drug combinations that kill thousands of Americans annually.

Unfortunately, the credulous coverage of Wal-Mart’s drug promotion is typical, not exceptional.

Last November, the company touted a self-commissioned study asserting that Wal-Mart saved $2,329 annually for an “average” household — a  remarkable claim that proved grossly inflated due to serious flaws in methodology. Yet national media outlets promptly trumpeted the results (some still cite the study) without offering any independent analysis.

Wal-Mart’s act had one positive impact—increasing awareness and price competition on generic drugs. But the massive promotion budgets of national chains can lead even critical thinkers to perceive, often wrongly, that chains provide greater value than our neighborhood businesses.

Reporters and editors should help their readers make fully-informed choices by providing independent analysis, not just a pro forma quote from a critic, when Wal-Mart issues its next press release.

Americans should know they don’t have to choose between competitive prices and quality service—they likely can receive both at local businesses that invest more in their products and services than for public relations campaigns.

Stacy Mitchell is a senior researcher with the Institute for Local Self-Reliance and is the author of Big-Box Swindle. Jeff Milchen co-directs American Independent Business Alliance.

© 2006 Jeff Milchen and Stacy Mitchell

Filed Under: Independent Business

Condemnation Nation

November 16, 2005 by staff

Retail chains and the big business of eminent domain

By Joshua Kurlantzick
First published by Harper’s Magazine, October, 2005

This June the Supreme Court handed down one of its most important property-rights decisions in decades. In Kelo v. New London, the Court ruled that the city of New London, Connecticut, could use eminent domain to seize homes–properties, the Court agreed, that were not “blighted or otherwise in poor condition”–from a handful of owners who refused to make way for a massive private redevelopment plan. The 5-4 decision confirmed the right of local governments to forcibly take property from one private owner and give it to another if the handover would presumably result in economic development–an affirmation of cities’ redefinition of the “public use” clause of the Fifth Amendment, which traditionally limited the taking of property to instances that benefited the larger public good. Indeed, throughout the nineteenth century and much of the twentieth, states invoked eminent domain primarily for these public uses, seizing smallholder land to build roads, parks, railroads, hospitals, and military bases.

In New London, however, the homes will not be replaced by a waterfront park or a school; they’ll make way for a conference center and hotel, an upscale office complex, and other structures designed to lure pharmaceutical giant Pfizer to the area–developments, it was successfully argued, that would bring increased tax revenue to economically distressed New London .

It was the Supreme Court’s more liberal jurists who voted in favor of New London , with Justice John Paul Stevens writing in the majority opinion that there “is no basis for exempting economic development from our traditionally broad understanding of public purpose.” Left-leaning editorial pages came out strongly in favor of the decision. The New York Times wrote that the ruling was “a welcome vindication of cities’ ability to act in the public interest.” “The court’s decision was correct,” agreed the Washington Post. Democratic leaders either touted the ruling or remained silent. Conservatives, on the other hand, quickly condemned the decision, with Florida Governor Jeb Bush calling it “horrible” and the Wall Street Journal opinion page, normally known for championing corporate interests, caustically noting that the Court’s liberals had given local governments “more or less unlimited authority to seize homes and businesses.” In her dissent, Justice Sandra Day O’Connor warned, “Nothing is to prevent the state from replacing any Motel 6 with a Ritz-Carlton, any home with a shopping mall, or any farm with a factory.”

This political divide, perhaps, shouldn’t be surprising. Liberals have historically supported government’s right to use broad powers to promote the greater social good–from protecting minorities and the poor to revitalizing faltering communities–and have had to defend this position against increasingly vituperative attacks from conservatives, who decry government programs as “not the solution to our problems” but “the problem.” Are liberals right, however, in claiming that eminent domain remains more solution than problem? Between 1998 and 2002, according to a study by the Institute of Justice, a public-interest law firm specializing in property rights, more than 10,000 properties in forty-one states were taken or threatened by eminent domain so that the land could be given to another private interest. And these numbers may actually be understated. In Maryland alone there were 1,237 of these private-interest threats or seizures. Of the more than 5,500 condemnations filed or threatened in California between 1998 and 2002, 858 are known to be on behalf of other private parties; it is impossible to know how many of the remaining thousands were as well.

What these numbers reflect is not some noble effort to revitalize America ‘s cities but a concerted campaign by city governments, on the one hand, and large real-estate developers and “big-box” retailers, on the other, to exploit eminent domain for their own gain. The developers and retailers–stores such as Wal-Mart and Target, which build numerous warehouse-style outlets on vast swaths of land to keep costs down–already enjoy immense advantages, including huge tax breaks, over smaller competitors; and yet increasingly they are urging cities to condemn property to serve their own interests, and employing lobbyists and donating large sums to local officials to help this effort. Cities, hoping to generate greater tax revenue, have been eager to comply, mostly to the detriment of homeowners and small businesses. To defend eminent domain as it is now practiced, therefore, is not a defense of our social compact with government, of the need for individuals to make sacrifices in the face of progress; it is an endorsement of a municipal-corporate collusion that now operates like a machine.

“The idea that you can invoke eminent domain is absolutely essential,” the mayor of Long Branch, New Jersey, Adam Schneider, explained to me. “Without that tool developers are not going to get on board.” And because companies now expect land seizure as part of their deal with cities, they will leverage the power of their tax revenues if city officials, their sizable economic redevelopment departments, or their hired private-public development corporations do not readily bend to their whims. In Long Beach , California, which has undergone extensive redevelopment of its waterfront and many commercial areas, the “developers are very well-versed in the legalities” of eminent domain, Councilman Frank Colonna told me. “The developers that get in are fully aware the city is committed to delivering the property, and would use eminent domain if we have to.” In the New London case, the president of Pfizer’s research department openly informed the city that if the company was to consider locating in New London, condemnation and redevelopment of adjacent areas would be vital. When megapharmacy chain CVS wanted to build a new drugstore in Ambridge, Pennsylvania, its local developer simply asked the government to seize the land and give it a lease; the town complied. In a more obscene flouting of public use, the city of Cypress, California, prevented a local church from building on property it had legally acquired in order to give the land to Costco.

Although cities and their development professionals at times select the land that they hope retailers will fill, in many cases retailers themselves find the choicest parcels of land, which they then ask cities to hand over. When Best Buy identified desirable land in Richfield, Minnesota, for the relocation and expansion of its corporate headquarters, Richfield guaranteed the company that it would use eminent domain to take property from the area’s existing businesses. In New Rochelle, New York, Ikea said it wanted to build a 300,000-square-foot store on fifteen acres of an existing neighborhood; the city agreed to clear the land, although public outcry later led Ikea to pull out of the deal. In fact, seeking sites with the idea of condemning them has become so routine that developers and retailers aren’t shy about their aims. A Costco vice president, in a frank letter to a shareholder in 2002, acknowledged that this was now normal operating procedure–that the company had initiated “dozens” of projects utilizing or threatening eminent domain to take away enough land from former tenants for its 148,000-square-foot stores. If Costco “refrained from participating in these deals,” the VP wrote, “our competitors for those sites, like Target, Home Depot, Kmart, Wal-Mart, BJ’s, Sam’s Club, and many others, would take advantage of our reticence.”

Even when a municipality’s economic-redevelopment agency is on board, developers and retailers must convince city councils and other elected officials that the condemnations are warranted. Consequently, developers and retailers have begun deploying, in unprecedented numbers, local lobbyists to win land concessions. According to the Center for Responsive Politics, the retail sales industry more than tripled its political contributions between 1990 and 2004; the real-estate industry’s contributions grew more than sevenfold during that same period.

In New York State alone, spending on municipal lobbying has grown from some $6 million per year in 1978 to $144 million in 2004, and the number of registered lobbyists has risen to over 3,800. In some cases the lobbying is blatantly venal. In Newark, New Jersey, for example, the city council was initially opposed to a redevelopment plan that involved seizing nine city blocks and 166 properties and building high-end condominiums in their place; when a coalition of developers contributed funds directly to two municipal councilmen, they suddenly changed their stance and allowed the proposal to go forward. In Lancaster, California, Costco repeatedly threatened to leave the city unless the municipality condemned a neighboring business, 99 Cents Only. Under pressure, the local government tried to entice the smaller store into leaving, then began proceedings to condemn its land. “99 Cents produces less than $40,000 [a year] in sales taxes,” the Lancaster city’s attorney reasoned. “And Costco was producing more than $400,000. You tell me which was more important.”

Cities and their officials have used eminent domain in other ways to line their pockets. The Southwestern Illinois Development Agency charged a commission fee for condemnations allotted for private use, in essence raising money directly from eminent domain. In Mesa, Arizona, and in Cincinnati, city council members or redevelopment-corporation board members either owned property that likely would have increased in value due to redevelopment or were themselves the contractors bidding on the lucrative construction projects.

Once the local government makes a decision to condemn, it still has to demonstrate to the public that the seizures are warranted. But this has turned out not to be difficult. It has become an accepted part of the process that a private developer can pay for a study showing the property is worthy of condemnation, and can pay the attorneys’ fees involved in seizing the land. (By comparison, the idea that pharmaceutical companies should pay a part of the Food and Drug Administration’s reviews of new medicines, a similar conflict of interest, has proven extremely controversial.) In St. Louis, Target and the city commissioned a blight study that showed a site’s electrical system was deteriorating. Yet the study failed to mention that Target was responsible for upkeep of the electricity at the site, where it already had one store, so the company itself had created the “blight” it then decried.

When such studies designate land as “blighted,” they make it easier for condemnation to proceed. But “blighted” is a subjective term, and definitions of blight vary widely from state to state. The city of Pittsburgh seized a neighborhood in which some 95 percent of the buildings were reportedly occupied. According to state redevelopment law, property can be declared blighted in New York if it lacks off-street parking. San Jose has marked a tenth of the entire city as blighted. After land is designated as blighted, the public is supposed to have a chance to respond. Yet cities and developers can essentially cut the public out of this process as well. In the St. Louis Target case, the city sent notice of the public hearing on condemnation to Target but not to the property holder. In other cases the municipality published these notices in the legal classifieds of local newspapers rather than sending information directly to property owners who stood to lose their land. When the government of Port Chester, New York, wanted to obtain parcels of land for a private developer, it published its notice of condemnation in the paper, without mentioning that landowners had only thirty days to challenge the order.

With a blight designation in hand, the city and the developer have considerable leverage. Most small landholders sell, since they rarely have the resources to fight the decision. Although states require the developer to pay “just compensation” for the land, this may not take into account the difference between what the city determines is fair market value and the property’s true open market value. Redevelopment officials in Port Chester offered one landowner less than half what local tax authorities said his property was worth. In Garden Grove, California, where the city wanted to redevelop large expanses of land, the municipal government offered only $16,000 for a successful auto business; a court later forced it to pay $950,000.

As this procedure has become increasingly routine, governments and developers have formed permanent partnerships, dangerously blurring the line between the public and private sectors. Almost all cities now have economic-development professionals, and these in turn have engendered their own trade associations. The National Congress for Community Economic Development, for one, has grown from a membership of forty development corporations in the early 1970s to over seven hundred today. And these development pros now have their own meeting and junket circuits, where they can rub shoulders with and woo retailers and developers. At one of the largest of these events, the International Council of Shopping Centers, held in Las Vegas, armies of retail executives, economic-development specialists, and officials from cities across the country mingle at booths designed to advertise a city’s appeal to big retail. A contingent from Fontana, California, at the 2005 International Council exposition included the mayor, his entire economic-development team, and several city councilors. “We want the private developer to show good faith in acquiring land,” Ray Bragg, Fontana ‘s redevelopment and special-projects director, told me. “And if you run up against a stumbling block, if you find a landowner unwilling to sell, come to us and then we’ll talk about eminent domain.”

In his majority opinion, Justice Stevens wrote, The City [of New London] has carefully formulated an economic-development plan that it believes will provide appreciable benefits to the community, including–but by no means limited to–new jobs and increased tax revenue.” It was the development plan, and its promise that the seizure of homes would result in positive change–in progress–that clinched the decision for the five consenting judges. Yet these plans, according to the Court’s ruling, need not provide “reasonable certainty” that the “expected public benefits will actually accrue.” Indeed, evidence suggests that cities’ efforts at redevelopment rarely bear fruit. A comprehensive study conducted in California in 1998 shows that cities spend roughly two dollars–on condemnations, the luring of companies, and other aspects of redevelopment–for every dollar gained in growth. In three out of every four of the areas it examined, the study found that redevelopment projects had brought no net increase in tax revenue.

This study is perhaps less surprising than it seems: in neighborhoods filled with small businesses, a few can close and the area will retain its economic center. But if a municipality condemns land and gives it to a big-box retailer and that chain doesn’t move in, or moves in and closes, a wide swath of land is left vacant. This history of condemnation or potential condemnation, moreover, discourages businesses from improving their stores, or new owners from moving in, since they never know when the city might take their land. In one case in Hampton, Virginia, the city condemned homes to build a project anchored by Kmart; then, in 2002, Kmart declared bankruptcy, itself a victim of even more pervasive big-box competitors. At the time, Kmart’s demise left the Hampton space an unused shell. In another case, in Phoenix , the city condemned a small tobacco shop for new development but ultimately found no takers, leaving the land vacant.

Kelo v. New London does include a proviso that may protect homeowners and small businesses from unproven redevelopment plans, with their alluring promises of greater revenue and profit: it sends the issue back to the states, which have the power to set their own standards on seizures. And eleven states already have put forward legislation that would significantly limit the Supreme Court ruling. Republicans in both the Texas House and Senate have proposed amendments to the state constitution prohibiting almost all instances in which eminent domain can be used for economic development or private gain. Tom McClintock, a conservative senator from California, has introduced a similar bill in his state. “No one should have to worry about losing your home to some politically connected developer,” he recently said. “There are 6,000 public agencies in California that now have the power to seize your home, pay you pennies on the dollar for it, and then give it to somebody else for their own personal gain and profit.” Libertarian groups have even proposed using eminent domain to seize the homes of Justices David Souter and Stephen Breyer, both of whom voted with the majority in the New London case.

Although condemnations fall most heavily on Democrats’ key constituencies–the poor and minorities-Democrats at the federal level have done little to try to ensure that eminent domain is used judiciously and constructively. By lending implicit if not explicit support to a flawed enterprise, Democrats are defending a principle–the government’s right to act on behalf of the greater good of its citizenry–that has been abused into obsolescence. And this support only confirms many voters’ fears (and the Republicans’ incessantly pushed portrayal) of the minority party as haughtily paternalistic, unresponsive to individual rights, uncaring about the needs of the little guy. In a pending Senate bill that would prevent all seizures for economic development, only two of the twenty-five cosponsors were Democrats; this summer, 157 Democrats in the House voted against a successful amendment to a bill that restricts transportation funds from being used for eminent domain takings. House Minority Leader Nancy Pelosi, one of the country’s most prominent and admittedly liberal Democrats, supported the New London decision, even saying, strangely, that the Court’s ruling was “as if God had spoken.” Apparently, these days, even God shops at Wal-Mart.

© 2005 Harper’s Magazine 

Related feature on corporate exploitation of eminent domain: Wal-Mart, the Abuse of Eminent Domain and Corporate Welfare

 

Filed Under: Corporate Welfare / Corporate Tax Issues, Independent Business, Walmart

Target vs. Wal-Mart

June 8, 2005 by staff

Is Target Corporation Any Better for Workers?

By Chris Serres
First published in the Minneapolis Star-Tribune in 2005

It was the fall of 2001, and a chorus of boos erupted at Target’s annual sales meeting when a senior executive at the company flashed Wal-Mart’s name and logo on an enlarged screen.

“This,” he said, pointing at the logo, “is the evil empire.”

For years, Target has cultivated an image of itself as the “anti-Wal-Mart,” a retailer that refuses to sacrifice workplace standards in the pursuit of higher sales and stock prices.

But now, after a decade of meteoric growth at both Target and Wal-Mart, labor groups say the two retailers are no longer very different in the way they treat their workers.

Entry-level hourly workers in Target stores earn roughly the same pay and have more difficulty qualifying for health care coverage than their peers at Wal-Mart. Both retailers oppose unions and have taken steps to prevent organizing efforts in stores. And both have outsourced jobs overseas to save costs.

But while Wal-Mart is perceived as a corporate giant that will do just about anything to maximize sales and profits, Target — thanks to its hip advertising campaigns and its longtime contributions to a variety of civic and cultural causes — is seen as a model corporate citizen and benevolent employer.

Accurate or not, Target’s image is a key advantage as it races to build more stores.

In “blue state” markets, such as the Twin Cities, Chicago and New York, Target is often welcomed with open arms by city leaders. Wal-Mart, meanwhile, faces community opposition at almost every turn, which has prevented it from expanding in many key markets, including New York City .

In West St. Paul, virtually no one challenged Target’s recent proposal to convert a new store to a SuperTarget. Yet 30 miles away in Ham Lake, Wal-Mart has spent more than a year trying — without success — to persuade city leaders to allow it to build a Supercenter.

“Some people, their hackles just go up when you mention Wal-Mart,” said Joseph Beaulieu, a retail analyst at Morningstar. “You could tell them that Wal-Mart pays more [than Target], but they would still be convinced that Wal-Mart is evil.”

But as Target continues its aggressive expansion — it plans to add more than 600 stores by 2010 — the company’s labor practices will come under more scrutiny from union groups, consumer advocates and local zoning boards, labor experts predict.

“Unless Target moves to improve its wages and benefits, it’s only a matter of time before it is seen as just another big-box retailer,” said Brendan Cummins, a Minneapolis labor attorney for the Miller O’Brien firm.

Already, Target is beginning to get some unwanted attention from labor groups that have been struggling to reform Wal-Mart’s workplace practices for nearly two decades.

Chief among them is the United Food and Commercial Workers union, the largest union of retail workers in the nation. The UFCW has been trying to organize Target workers for years, without success. This week, about a dozen members of the UFCW tried to call attention to Target’s wages and benefits by protesting outside the company’s annual shareholder meeting in Minneapolis .

One of Target’s newest critics is its main competitor, Wal-Mart. At a recent media conference in Bentonville, Ark., Wal-Mart executives accused Target of offering a less attractive benefit package and challenged reporters to conduct a comparison of their own.

Asked to respond to Wal-Mart’s criticisms at Target’s annual meeting, CEO Bob Ulrich said he “didn’t really know what Wal-Mart pays” its workers but said that Target conducts regular wage surveys in all its markets to ensure it pays competitive wages.

“We believe Target is a great place to shop and to work,” Ulrich said. “We have no difficulty attracting terrific team members.”

Ulrich also defended the Target’s antiunion stance, saying that the company “simply doesn’t believe that third-party representation would add anything for our customers, our employees or our shareholders. We just do not believe it’s productive and adds value.”

Few differences
Target declined to disclose details about its compensation and benefits, but labor groups and former and current employees of Target in the Twin Cities say the retailer sometimes pays less than Wal-Mart.

Target pays between $6.25 an hour to $8 an hour for entry-level, hourly positions in its Twin Cities stores, according to a recent survey of local Target workers by the UFCW. That’s in line with what Wal-Mart pays in this market, though some starting-level Wal-Mart workers can earn $9 to $10 an hour, the UFCW said.

Both companies offer health care insurance to employees, but Target’s is considered more restrictive. Two years ago, Target dropped health care insurance coverage for all part-time workers. By contrast, Wal-Mart makes its medical plan available to all workers, full- and part-time.

Union groups that have analyzed the two companies’ policies maintain that Wal-Mart’s also is more equitable.

All Wal-Mart’s employees, from store cashiers to chief executive Lee Scott, are covered under the same medical plan. All employees can choose from the same four deductible options and receive unlimited coverage for catastrophic expenses — such as organ transplants or cancer treatments — that can financially ruin an employee.

Target, however, offers multiple health care plans to its employees that vary by geographic location, according to the company’s employee handbook. At Target, store employees do not receive catastrophic coverage and deductible levels vary, according to former and current employees.

Wal-Mart estimates that 56 percent of its employees receive health care coverage. Target declined to disclose its percentage of insured workers, but the UFCW estimates based on surveys of Twin Cities employees that less than half the company’s workers receive coverage under its plan.

Target declined to contribute wage and benefit information for this article but said the data cited by others were inaccurate.

“Target has one of the best health care and benefits packages in the industry,” company spokeswoman Carolyn Brookter said in a prepared statement. “We are an industry leader in providing a wide array of excellent benefits that allow us to attract and retain the best team members.”

However, the UFCW and others interviewed for this story stand by their information. “The only difference between Target and Wal-Mart is that Wal-Mart is six times their size,” said Bernie Hesse, a union organizer with UFCW Local 789 in St. Paul .

Wages and benefits are not the only criteria of a good workplace, and many employees at Target insist it’s still a much better place to work than Wal-Mart.

The company is flexible with employees who want to work part-time and spend time with their families. Its 401(k) retirement plan is considered among the best in the retail industry; it matches, dollar for dollar, up to 5 percent of all contributions made by employes. And all new workers receive a 10 percent discount on most merchandise purchased at Target.

“As far as its flexibility, Target was a wonderful place to work,” said Jennifer Clark, who worked at a Target store in Mission Viejo, Calif., before moving to Reno, Nev., last year to become an executive recruiter. “If I told the manager that my daughter was receiving an award at school and I needed to leave early, he’d say, ‘Sure, go ahead. Take care of your family first.’ ”

Mary Murphy, 39, of Chanhassen said she was proud when Target hired her as a cashier. She liked working for a company that gives 5 percent of its federally taxable income to the communities where it does business, which amounts to about $2 million a week.

And she was impressed by Target’s “Take Charge of Education” program, through which credit-card holders can donate 1 percent a year of their Target Guest Card purchases made at Target to a school of their choice. Target also donates 0.5 percent of all Target Visa purchases made everywhere Visa is accepted. Through this program, Target has donated about $138 million to schools nationwide since 1997.

Working at Target’s main rival, Wal-Mart, was out of the question, Murphy said. She never liked the store’s crowded aisles, fluorescent lights and “all-around messiness.” The mother of four also was turned off by reports that the company had violated child labor laws and discriminated against women by paying them less than men for many of the same jobs.

“I can’t stand shopping at Wal-Mart, much less work there,” Murphy said. Yet Murphy is no longer convinced that accepting a job at Target was the right decision. Hired as a cashier at $7.50 an hour, Murphy was told that she could receive a 50-cent raise, but she was expected to meet Target’s quota of selling at least nine credit cards a week to shoppers.

Managers would hover near the checkout lanes to make sure cashiers were pitching the cards with “the proper enthusiasm,” Murphy said. They were required to vary how they pitched the cards so they wouldn’t annoy repeat customers, but Murphy said she found the quota impossible to attain.

“I hired on to be a cashier, but they wanted us to be telemarketers,” she said. “I didn’t want to be known in the community as the ‘Target Red Card pusher.’ ” Murphy resigned after nine months without ever receiving the raise, yet she still considers herself more fortunate than many of the other cashiers at the store.

Her husband, an electrical engineer, has health care coverage for the entire family through his employer. And her pay, though low, was about 25 cents higher per hour than some starting-level workers in the Chanhassen store. Murphy said that between 25 to 30 cashiers worked at the Chanhassen store at the same time she started. After nine months, she said she was the only one remaining. “If there was a union and a sense that things were going to improve, people might have stayed longer,” Murphy said. “Right now, there is absolutely no incentive to stay there for any length of time.”

John Hayden, 59, of Oconomowoc, Wis., lasted just six months loading and unloading boxes at a Target distribution center near his home.

Hayden said he liked his co-workers and managers, but he said the work was simply too difficult for the wage — $11 an hour. Hayden said he occasionally had to unload tractor trailers full of 75-pound boxes. Target encouraged employees to request help with heavy boxes, but the loading deadlines were so strict that Hayden often had to load them himself.

A year after leaving the company, Hayden learned that he had a hernia and had to undergo surgery, which he blames on the stress of lifting up to 700 boxes a day. “There were some nights, I could barely move,” Hayden said.

To motivate its warehouse workers, managers often offered employees small gifts, such as coasters or flashlights with the Target logo, if they beat their goals. “They treated us like third-graders, like we wouldn’t work hard without gifts,” he said. “It was insulting to older workers.”

Hayden considered applying for work at a Wal-Mart store in nearby Delafield, Wis., after hearing from colleagues that it paid 50 cents to $1 more per hour.

“Two years ago, I’d say it doesn’t matter, Target or Wal-Mart, I’d work for either one,” Hayden said. “But now, after working at Target, I’d choose Wal-Mart.”

For the time being, however, Wal-Mart remains the No. 1 target for union organizers, largely because of its size. The company employs 1.7 million people worldwide and is the nation’s largest private employer. Its sales totaled $285 billion in 2005, more than the combined revenue of Target, Sears and Costco.

Two national groups have sprouted up over the past nine months that have a single purpose — to reform Wal-Mart.

One, “Wake-Up Wal-Mart,” is funded by the UFCW and is run by Paul Blank, the former political director of former Democratic presidential candidate Howard Dean. In less than two months, the group has amassed 50,000 members, an army of people that can distribute information about Wal-Mart’s labor practices and to oppose new stores.

Union groups have to focus on Wal-Mart because until the nation’s largest retailer alters its labor practices, companies like Target will have no incentive to change, Blank added.

“No one here is excusing Target or anyone else for failing to live up to its responsibilities to its workers,” Blank said. “But how do you change these very large companies? You have to go after the source of the problem, and that’s still Wal-Mart.”

© 2005 Minneapolis Star-Tribune

Related:

  • Walmart vs Target Redux: More Alike Than You Think
  • Why we encourage those who care about the impacts of their purchases to choose independent locally-owned businesses.
  • See our huge collection of articles, studies, internal documents and more on Wal-Mart and big box stores.  
  • Visit our Merchandise Page to see anti-Walmart stickers, t-shirts and more.

Filed Under: Independent Business, Walmart

Ranchers and Dairy Farmers Win Two Battles Against Corporate and Government Foes

July 18, 2004 by staff

By Jennifer Rockne
First published in the spring 2004 Insurgent

In a potentially transformative federal court decision, ranchers won a class-action lawsuit against the meatpacking giant, Tyson Foods, Inc., for violating the Packers and Stockyards Act of 1921 — created to protect farmers from the tyranny of that era’s meat giants. The suit was filed in 1996, when Tyson was known as IBP Inc. Tyson was ordered to pay $1.28 billion, spread among up to 35,000 ranchers. The corporation’s attorneys vowed to appeal the Alabama jury’s decision.

The system of regional meatpackers and competitive markets has given way to one in which producers sell, usually by pre-arranged contract, to any of four massive corporations — Cargill/Excel, Tyson/IBP, Farmland National Beef, and Swift/ConAgra, which jointly control nearly 85% of the market.

The Tyson case, and others pending against Cargill/Excel and Swift/ConAgra, stems from a practice in which cattle buyers contract for cattle ahead of the time of sale, then “store” the cattle to drop the bidding price. The Tyson verdict is the largest to date against anti-trust law abuse known as monopsony (or oligopsony), the opposite of monopoly. In a monopoly, the seller raises prices paid by buyers, while in a monopsony, a dominant company uses its market power to depress the prices it pays suppliers below what they would receive in a competitive market.

Though the meat processing industry is an oligopsony nationally (Tyson controls about a third of the market), a single company often enjoys a monopsony in a particular region.

Increased corporate concentration and lack of federal enforcement of anti-trust law across several industries is sparking a wave of civil litigation. The Tyson verdict is an encouraging sign that some courts may enforce laws that industry-coopted regulators are failing to uphold.

Meanwhile, on Feb. 24, the 3rd Circuit U.S. Appeals Court ruled a national milk “check-off” fee unconstitutional on grounds that it violates First Amendment rights. The plaintiffs in Cochran v. Veneman (Ann Veneman, U.S. Secretary of Agriculture) were family farmers who raised free-range, hormone-free cows. They believed the mandatory fee, collected by the federal government to promote milk as a generic commodity, undermined their product and amounted to forced speech with which they disagreed.

Federally-mandated commodity checkoffs are now 0 for 3 in recent appeals court rulings. Pork and beef check-offs (the beef case is under appeal to the U.S. Supreme Court) also were ruled unconstitutional for the same reasons as the milk fee.

Similar legal challenges have been waged with initial success in the grape, mushroom and pork industries.

Filed Under: Independent Business

  • « Previous Page
  • 1
  • 2
  • 3
  • Next Page »

Search our website

Our Mission

Reclaim Democracy! works toward a more democratic republic, where citizens play an active role in shaping our communities, states, and nation. We believe a person’s influence should be based on the quality of their ideas, skills, and energy, and not based on wealth, race, gender, or orientation.

We believe every citizen should enjoy an affirmative right to vote and have their vote count equally.

Learn more about our work.

Donate to Our Work

We rely on individual gifts for more than 95% of our funding. Our hard-working volunteers make your gift go a long way. We're grateful for your help, and your donation is tax-deductible.

Join Us on Social Media

  • Facebook
  • Twitter

Weekly Quote

"The great enemy of freedom is the alignment of political power with wealth."

-- Wendell Berry

Copyright © 2025 · Reclaim Democracy!